It’s great to know that people take note of the ideas we share on this blog. In April, I posted an entry introducing a paper I had recently presented in Croatia, called “Attempting the Production of Public Goods through Microfinance: The Case of Water and Sanitation“. The argument was that water and sanitation, because they have the characteristics of public goods, cannot be provided adequately via private individual credit like microfinance loans.
In a thoughtful article on microfinancefocus.com Katya Jenkins recently re-iterated this point (and quoted the paper). Her basic argument: some organisations are reporting successes, but we have good reasons to be skeptical, and it might not work in every case.
Jenkins makes one very important point at the end, which is that there may be a better case for small self-financing in water and sanitation if we were talking about community systems. Agreed. But microfinance organisations would have to adapt their business models a lot, giving out much larger loans (€ millions rather than hundreds), being far more patient with repayments (slower repayment means slower turnover means lower profits), and actually bothering to “know” their clients’ business (instead of easy and cheap “no questions asked” lending). That’s a long shot from today’s microfinance, even if a select few organisations like ProCredit have taken the step into SME finance; and probably “microfinance” would be the wrong name for it.
The question still remains about the impact of microfinance models for water and sanitation. Not that a reduction in water-fetching time for a Zambian or Bangla lady from 3 hours a day to 15 minutes wouldn’t be a great thing – of course it would – but the fact remains that everyone who reads this blog (or Water.org‘s success stories) has a tap which they simply can turn on and a toilet which flushes, and they would not be succeeding in life without them.
I have grave doubts that microfinance, or private enterprise in general, could ever emulate this fantastic achievement of the public sector. So why bother with trying to make third-best solutions work? At best microfinance models could be a stopgap in lieu of something far better. To quote the wise words of Lant Pritchett (in a comment on Roodman’s blog):
I was living in India and discussing arrangements for household water supply with some development colleagues of mine. After about half an hour of pretty fruitless discussion I said, “let’s step back. tell me your long-run vision of the household water sector in India” They said “Our vision is that India meets the target that every household lives within half a kilometer of an improved water source capable of providing 40 liters of safe per person per day.” I said, “I see the problem. My vision of success is that every Indian can take a hot shower inside their own home.” The difference is that one can imagine meeting the first goal “programmatically” or with a series of “interventions” while the latter clearly requires endogenously functional systems. No one I know wants to have to go to a group meeting to take a hot shower. They want to turn the tap and it works.
(phil)
4 comments
Comments feed for this article
June 6, 2011 at 11:30
leonidobusch
While I agree with your overall argument I am asking myself, whether loans of millions of euros can be subsumed under “microfinance” anyway?
Or is it that we can observe a shift in meaning of the word microfinance away from being restricted to (very) small loans to (poor) individuals in the direction of giving loans to people and associations (in developing countries) that don’t have access to loans from classical banks (independent of the size of the loan)?
June 6, 2011 at 11:51
philmader
Absolutely! I too wonder whether “microfinance” is still an adequate name for projects of such scale.
The shift you describe is taking place – not formally, but in practice. I mentioned ProCredit which started with a simple and tiny “Grameen-replicator” model, learned lessons, and is now financing medium-sized enterprises with dozens of employees using loans above 10 million Euros. Or there is BASIX in India which is organising co-operatives and conducting business training for small-scale employers.
Official microfinance discourse on the other hand still is firmly stuck in the notion of financing individuals through groups via “credit only”. It remains to be seen whether the shifts in practice by some successful organisations (on its balance sheet in the case of ProCredit; and on measures of social impact in the case of BASIX) are going change the official discourse.
Once again, however, the question would arise whether if we are funding “Mittelständler” or conducting business training sessions we should call it microfinance; or not “SME finance” (ProCredit) or “livelihood promotion” (BASIX) instead. Perhaps the only logical reason to subsume communal water treatment plants with an investment cost of €100,000 or 1,000,000 under the name “microfinance” (as the influential Gates Foundation report in 2008 did) would be because donors are more likely to take a liking to a project if it calls itself “microfinance”. While misleading (“self-finance” would be clearer), perhaps that is as good a reason as any?
June 6, 2011 at 13:25
leonidobusch
You’re probably right that the attractiveness of the term “microfinance” is important here. Especially because of the nobel prize for peace, “microfinance” is considered to be “good” or “ethical” whereas the similarly or maybe even more important issue of credit for SMEs in developing countries lacks such a catchy denomination…
June 6, 2011 at 14:01
philmader
Well-said. It ties in with Domen’s explanation of how new concepts or activities in development assistance have to be marketed.